Developing countries today target high growth through investments in
infrastructure, modernization and expansion of manufacturing and service
facilities, and in agriculture and allied areas. At the same time, they seek to
enable disadvantaged sections to upgrade their standard of living. In this, the
developing countries expect financial institutions to act aggressively as well
as responsibly.
The global financial structure,
as it is evolving, is a technological marvel. Assets originating at the base
are securitized, packaged in different forms for sale to investors all across
the globe. These assets, if infected with a high probability of default, will
always carry the germs of a systemic crisis. The lending agencies therefore
have an enormous(large,विशाल) responsibility; while a high-growth economy offers
opportunities for profits, lenders need to be (despite insistent pressures from
powerful borrowers and politicians) extremely cautious and desist from taking
on high-risk assets.
A good example in this regard is
the subprime crisis in the US during the decade just gone by. The lending
ambience was congenial(favourable,अनुकूल) : a continually
rising property market, a flood of liquidity fed by an upsurge in global
savings and an accommodating credit policy. The lenders had two options: low
profit, low risk from sound but relatively few mortgage assets, and high
profit, high risk from high risk but abundant(excessive,अत्यधिक) mortgage assets.
Lending agencies chose the second
option—a choice dictated by the inexorable(harsh,कठोर) logic of a
profit-driven market economy. They lured(entice,लुभाना) subprime borrowers
with a slew of “innovations” to create assets at any cost: progressively
relaxing margin money, dispensing with the requirement of income investigation
and dismissing borrower concerns about unexpected shortfalls in their
disposable incomes. All this they did, not out of any philanthropic(generous,परोपकारी) zeal but out of the
urge(force,मजबूर) (given the opportunity) to make quick profits. The major
premise underlying their behaviour was that if the property market collapsed,
leading to a systemic crisis, the state could not but step in, as it had indeed
done several times in the past.
State intervention in a crisis is
a must, but the challenge before any polity is to intervene before the crisis
erupts and to do so in a manner that helps the lending agencies generate a
sustainable level of good assets. Such intervention must be planned and
designed such that a balance is struck between the aspiration of marginal
borrowers (to create and own assets) and the continued viability of lending
agencies—critical for the efficiency and stability of any financial system. If
we are to grapple(fight,लड़ना) with the recurring problem of non-performing assets and
continue uninterruptedly with pushing social sector lending and infrastructure
development, the polity has to act innovatively: There has to be a partnership,
so to speak, between the state and the financial system.
But what kind of a partnership?
Two points need to be made here. The plea for state participation is not to
seek a return to the “loan mela”
days of political patronage, to open the purse strings for subsidies, to
interfere with the credit decisions of lending agencies, or to justify the
oft-talked about practice of lending at political behest. This is a plea for
selective public investment aimed at enhancing(increase,बढ़ाना) the viability of
private sector projects and the income and employment potentials for the
disadvantaged sectors.
Take housing, for instance. Our
desire to have a pool of affordable houses has hardly made any headway,
primarily because of the prohibitive cost of land. The state has to do some
out-of-the-box thinking to clear the hurdles(problem,बाधा) in the availability of
land at a reasonable price. The flow of funds from the state and the lending
agencies, made available in tandem(one behind other,एक के बाद एक) and planned and
targeted at select locations, should be the basis for this partnership.
A second point. Admittedly, we
have to push private sector investments into different types of infrastructure
projects, industry and agriculture for sustaining growth and generating employment.
In this regard, a good many projects are clearly viable and remain good
candidates for institutional funding, even as several others continue to
inhabit the penumbra zone. Given the technological complexities and demand in
today’s dynamic global economy, and with the kind of in-house skills currently
available, the projects of the latter variety do not lend themselves to easy
appraisal. It is also next to impossible for individual lending agencies to
cost-effectively build in-house skills for the accurate evaluation of these
projects. If investments in all key sectors are to be pushed aggressively, we
must have special institutions with the mandate to assess these projects and to
provide such critical financial assistance as can induce the lending institutions
to lend appropriately to them.
We had set up development finance institutions in the early
stages of our industrialization in the 1950s and early 1960s; nearly 75% of the
cumulate private investment was canalized through these. However, we committed
the grievous(serious,गंभीर) mistake of scrapping these institutions in the 1990s. On
the other hand, China, years after it had switched over to a market economy,
set up its National Development Bank in 1995; the institution is estimated to
have financed over 60% of the total private investment in that country since
then. Brazil is another illustrious example in this regard, while even Germany
and Japan are continuing with these types of development banks.
Back home, in India, we must recognize that, without the
critical support, financial and otherwise, that such national-level development
finance institutions can provide, our objective of creating a sustainable level
of good assets and maintaining a steady rate of growth is bound to remain
hamstrung.
No comments:
Post a Comment